In May 1992, a ‘Plea for a Pluralistic and Rigorous Economics’ was
published in the American Economic Review (Vol 82 No. 2). It was signed by Harcourt, Galbraith,
Goodwin, Kindelberger, Minsky, Pasinetti and other eminent economists. The Plea
was funded by FEED who launched a second ‘Plea’
in 2009 and support the 2012 ‘Manifesto for Economic
Sense’. Geoffrey Hodgson, Research
Professor in Business Studies at the University of Hertfordshire and one
of the co-organisers of the ‘1992 Plea’, is interviewed here about the history
of economic pluralism, and the challenges facing economics today.
NL: Twenty two years after the ‘1992 Plea’, do you think the
mainstream has changed?
GH: I think things have changed in economics, to some degree. It’s
not entirely positive, but in some senses economics is more diverse now that it
was twenty two years ago… for example, new areas like experimental economics
and behavioural economics have gained respectability. The main problem now with
economics is not so much its diversity, or its insufficient internal pluralism,
but the way that technique dominates and gets in the way of substance.
Economists are engaged with mathematical puzzle solving rather than real-world
problems…
NL: By that you mean things like regression analysis and
theoretical model building?
GH: Theoretical model building and econometrics … that is all that
now seems to matter in terms of publication in top journals or academic
promotion. The whole discipline has become dominated by people who are very
clever in technique but innocent of many important aspects of the real world
and the history of their own discipline.
NL: In that 1992 Edition of the AER there were some pluralist
surveys of economists, do you think the AER would publish that kind of
qualitative research today?
GH: Generally it is very difficult to publish anything like that,
and not just in the AER. I include other leading journals, like the Quarterly
Journal of Economics or the Economic Journal in the UK… although occasionally
they publish qualitative pieces, to spice up interest in their journal.
NL: What successes have you seen in the campaign for pluralism?
GH: The ‘1992 Plea’ was an early ringing of alarm bells about the
nature of the discipline and the way it had been developing. It may have
stimulated further similar complaints, such as from the French student
movement… and dispersed attempts in Cambridge and also in the US… but the real
change came with the 2008 crash. This provoked a much larger tide of complaint
among students and others about the alleged inadequacies of mainstream
economics.
NL: Was there a pluralist movement prior to the ‘1992 Plea’?
GH: Several prominent economists had made complaints. The petition
was preceded by an important 1988 report by a commission of the American
Economics Association, called ‘Report by the Commission on Graduate Education’
(Krueger et al, 1991), which complained about the dominance of technique in the
discipline. A number of leading individuals, including Milton Friedman, also
complained about the subject turning into advanced mathematics. The most
important event was the 1988 commission and its critical and scathing report.
NL: Did it have any success at the time?
GH: No.
NL: So why do you think the profession keeps coming back to these
very inward-looking methods?
GH: The economics profession has an internal reward system that
gets reinforced and replicated. Someone once compared it to the peacock’s tail.
Once this positive feedback loop gets established, then people look for the
glorious tail feathers despite their questionable usefulness. Fancy mathematics
gets economists published and gets them promoted. As those people rise in the
profession they will recruit people who perform similarly and the same kind of
behaviour gets replicated. Other people, who think more widely or
philosophically, or are more interested in the history of the subject or how it
has changed, or who look more deeply at the conceptual assumptions, don’t get
considered for influential positions in the discipline.
NL: What advice would you give Rethinking Economics?
GH: I hate to be pessimistic, because I don’t want to dampen the
enthusiasm of those people committed to this, but unless you get some of the
top universities appointing professors who are more broad-minded, who are not
dominated by technique, who have influence, and some of the top journals
consider more conceptual, historical material rather than simply
technique-driven material, then it will fail. Mark Blaug, who was a
friend of mine who died a couple of years ago, got very pessimistic about this,
and so did Ronald Coase who died last year. Another problem is that American
economics is now overwhelmingly dominant. I often ask people… can you name a
living British economist… and they really have difficulty thinking of anybody.
When mainstream economists took over the Cambridge department in the 1980s,
after the era of Robinson and Kaldor, their explicit aim was to make Cambridge
a rival to the top American Universities In other words, they aimed not to
develop Cambridge’s own niche, but simply to follow what America was doing. You
are inevitably 5 years behind if you are lucky, and that US emulation has led
to the near-destruction of British economics… with this subservient mentality
it is very difficult to change things in the UK.
NL: Can we talk about your hope for the future?
You may have heard of a new association called WINIR:
the World Interdisciplinary Network for Institutional Research. What we are
trying to do is create a new field for study. It’s not just about economics,
but institutional economics is a part. I think that this is a more productive
strategy than trying to change economics… but the problem with WINIR is
it doesn’t cover everything. At the moment, it omits crucial areas like
finance... we can’t do everything. We are hoping to find new ways of promoting
realist approaches and developing new ideas
NL: When you look at Blanchard’s work at the IMF… is there
at least a sense that more reflective research is coming out, even on the
finance side?
GH: That’s right, and there are other good examples, like Thomas
Piketty’s work on capital and inequality…. but these are the exceptions. All
the incentives, all the ways that you get promoted in the system are not
by thinking outside of the box. When I gave a talk to the Post-Crash group in
Manchester, I said you have to take the institutions of science seriously. One
of the problems with heterodox criticism is that it’s a fragmented growth of
people who can’t agree amongst themselves on much, except that they are opposed
to the mainstream: that will never generate cumulative knowledge. We
actually need an alternative centre of orthodoxy. Science cannot progress by
questioning everything, all the time…. some assumptions or knowledge has
to be taken for granted. These assumptions may need to be changed later, but we
need consensus as much as pluralism. Hence I’m against organising opposition to
mainstream economics on the basis of a ‘heterodox’ label… in fact there
are many good and interesting things going on in the mainstream.
Heterodox organisations and leading figures who work under that label often overlook
potential allies in the mainstream…
NL: One of the things we are struggling with in the UK curriculum review is
the word ‘CORE’… this Popperian idea of a heuristic around which everything
else revolves… is the idea of a ‘CORE’ something the profession can
escape?
GH: I think the CORE idea is important: the problem with things at
the moment is that the core is defined in terms of technical skills. An
undergraduate doing an economics degree has to understand key aspects of game
theory, to understand key certain econometric techniques, and these take up the
time of teaching and testing for the student… and as the bar is always being
lifted… because the complexities of game theory and econometrics are always
increasing… so it’s not so much changing the subject matter of the core,
it’s changing the preoccupation of the core. We need to establish that the
first and foremost job of an economist is to understand the economy… all
other things are subservient to that.
Many heterodox economists blame Marshall, among others, for what
went wrong. He was part of the neoclassical revolution of the 1870s and 1880s.
But if you actually look at how Marshall wrote and how he behaved he was
extremely tolerant and open minded… he wrote in his Principles and also
in his letters that economic theory is not a mathematical toy. He argued that
we have to understand the real world. For him, mathematics was a tool, but not
the main part of the subject…
NL: Several of the petitions for pluralism talk about solving
climate change, global warming, inequality, wealth accumulation, capital
flight, all of these issues. Do you agree that economics is that broad? Can
economics solve all of these problems or is that too grand a claim?
GH: Marshall’s definition of economics was the study mankind
in the ordinary business of life: by that he meant processes concerning the
generation of wealth and its distribution, which include problems like the
impact of climate change… we need to develop economic policies to deal
with climate change in some way.
NL: Which includes solving these issues...
GH: Yes.
NL: Could you recommend three pieces of your work to a student
interested in pluralism?
GH: My 2004 book on institutional economics; my 2013 book on
evolutionary economics; and my book on capitalism that is coming out this year.
Each book addresses the issue of pluralism and challenges mainstream assumptions.
References
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2004) The
Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in
American Institutionalism (London
and New York: Routledge).
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2013) From
Pleasure Machines to Moral Communities: An Evolutionary Economics without Homo
Economicus (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press).
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (forthcoming) Conceptualizing Capitalism:
Institutions, Evolution, Future (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press).
Krueger, A.O. Arrow, K.J. et al (1991). Report of the commission
on graduate education in economics. Journal
of Economic Literature. 29(3):1035-1053
Various (1992). A Plea for a Pluralistic and Rigorous
Economics", American Economic Review, 82(2):25
No comments:
Post a Comment